Joseph Schumpeter


Also found in: Dictionary, Thesaurus, Wikipedia.

Schumpeter, Joseph

 

Born Feb. 8, 1883, in Triesch (now Třešt’), Moravia; died Jan. 8,1950, inTaconic, Conn. Economist and sociologist.

Educated at the University of Vienna, Schumpeter served as finance minister of Austria in 1919 and 1920. He was a professor at the University of Bonn from 1925 to 1932 and at Harvard University from 1932 until his death. He regarded the history of the discipline of political economy as the development of an analytical framework and of research methods for studying economic phenomena.

Schumpeter is known primarily for his concept of economic dynamics, which assigned a central place to the entrepreneurial function. He advanced the theory of efficient competition, which depicts the market mechanism in the era of big business as the fruitful interaction of the forces of monopoly and competition. These forces are fueled by innovations and impart a particular dynamism to economic development.

Schumpeter worked out the dynamic concept of the business cycle, in which recurrent business cycles are seen as a law of economic growth. According to this concept, the driving force behind prosperity is mass investment, embodying certain innovations, in fixed capital. In Schumpeter’s view, crises are not inevitable but occur when the natural cessation of an economic boom is met by panic. The theory of cycles assigns a major role to credit, which brings additional economic resources into play and thereby helps to implement innovations. Schumpeter attempted to refute the Marxist theory of socialist revolution by arguing that capitalist free enterprise would inevitaby be transformed, gradually, into an economic system whose development would be regulated and directed by the state.

WORKS

The Theory of Economic Development. New York, 1961.
Business Cycles, vols. 1–2. New York—London, 1939.
Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, 3rd ed. New York, 1950.
Ten Great Economists. New York [1951].
History of Economic Analysis. London [1967].

REFERENCES

Al’ter, L. B. Burzhuaznaia politicheskaia ekonomiia SShA. Moscow, 1961.
Seligman, B. Osnovnye techeniia sovremennoi ekonomicheskoi mysli. Moscow, 1968. Chapter 8. (Translated from English.)
Clemence, R. V., and F. S. Doody. The Schumpeterian System. Cambridge, Mass., 1950.
Schumpeter: Social Scientist. Edited by E. Harris. Cambridge, Mass., 1951.
Schneider, E., and G. Spiethoff, eds. Aufsätze zur ökonomischenTheorie. Tübingen, 1952.

K. B. KOZLOVA

References in periodicals archive ?
(7.) Joseph Schumpeter, Teoria del desenvolvimiento, op cit., pp.
Joseph Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (New York: Harper & Row, 1942), pp.
Carter take a personal approach, comparing Leontief with Joseph Schumpeter. While these two European intellectuals had different ways of doing economics, dynamics and changes in technology interested both of them.
The demise of these once profitable companies may well reflect their failure to sustain a position in their own market and as a global player when severely tested by what Joseph Schumpeter, the great Austrian-American economist of the 1930s and 1940s, described as "creative destruction".
In the middle of the 20th century, the Austrian economist and sociologist Joseph Schumpeter developed the theory of "creative destruction," which holds that innovative technology revolutionizes the economy from within.
Joseph Schumpeter, Austrian finance minister and professor of economics at Bonn and then Harvard University, amused himself and his classes with jokes widely circulated among students.
Indeed, "creative destruction," as Joseph Schumpeter put it, is often an important element of renewal in a dynamic market economy, but an efficient bankruptcy statute is required to aid in this process, including in the case of cross-border defaults.
CEOs and their companies are living through what Joseph Schumpeter called "creative destruction," a bloody but necessary way capitalism renews itself.
At a time when much of the research emanating from contemporary social science and humanities departments consists of chronicling the class struggle or cataloging mathematical techniques, Parker mixes history, economics, and sociology in a style that--in its breadth and penetration--reminds one of such great scholars as Joseph Schumpeter, Werner Sombart, and, more recently, Alfred D.
In a tradition going back to Joseph Schumpeter and Thorstein Veblen, they consider organizations as under-appreciated source of competition in markets while trying to understand individuals as learning agents not passively at the whim or organizational dynamics.
The Austrian economist Joseph Schumpeter's famous concept of growth via "creative destruction" had particular impact on cities.
Allen has written a number of splendid important books over his working life, starting with his highly original and beautifully presented volumes on the early Marx, next, taking in Adolph Lowe and Joseph Schumpeter (both heroes of mine), and finally his deep studies of the nature of Austrian economics past and present.