Joseph Schumpeter


Also found in: Dictionary, Thesaurus, Wikipedia.

Schumpeter, Joseph

 

Born Feb. 8, 1883, in Triesch (now Třešt’), Moravia; died Jan. 8,1950, inTaconic, Conn. Economist and sociologist.

Educated at the University of Vienna, Schumpeter served as finance minister of Austria in 1919 and 1920. He was a professor at the University of Bonn from 1925 to 1932 and at Harvard University from 1932 until his death. He regarded the history of the discipline of political economy as the development of an analytical framework and of research methods for studying economic phenomena.

Schumpeter is known primarily for his concept of economic dynamics, which assigned a central place to the entrepreneurial function. He advanced the theory of efficient competition, which depicts the market mechanism in the era of big business as the fruitful interaction of the forces of monopoly and competition. These forces are fueled by innovations and impart a particular dynamism to economic development.

Schumpeter worked out the dynamic concept of the business cycle, in which recurrent business cycles are seen as a law of economic growth. According to this concept, the driving force behind prosperity is mass investment, embodying certain innovations, in fixed capital. In Schumpeter’s view, crises are not inevitable but occur when the natural cessation of an economic boom is met by panic. The theory of cycles assigns a major role to credit, which brings additional economic resources into play and thereby helps to implement innovations. Schumpeter attempted to refute the Marxist theory of socialist revolution by arguing that capitalist free enterprise would inevitaby be transformed, gradually, into an economic system whose development would be regulated and directed by the state.

WORKS

The Theory of Economic Development. New York, 1961.
Business Cycles, vols. 1–2. New York—London, 1939.
Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, 3rd ed. New York, 1950.
Ten Great Economists. New York [1951].
History of Economic Analysis. London [1967].

REFERENCES

Al’ter, L. B. Burzhuaznaia politicheskaia ekonomiia SShA. Moscow, 1961.
Seligman, B. Osnovnye techeniia sovremennoi ekonomicheskoi mysli. Moscow, 1968. Chapter 8. (Translated from English.)
Clemence, R. V., and F. S. Doody. The Schumpeterian System. Cambridge, Mass., 1950.
Schumpeter: Social Scientist. Edited by E. Harris. Cambridge, Mass., 1951.
Schneider, E., and G. Spiethoff, eds. Aufsätze zur ökonomischenTheorie. Tübingen, 1952.

K. B. KOZLOVA

References in periodicals archive ?
I'm inclined to draw on two founds of wisdom for answers: Milton Friedman and Joseph Schumpeter.
As the underlying economic theory, he adopted the thinking of a fellow Austrian, Joseph Schumpeter.
High demand goods are a particular case of innovation which is perceived by the economist Joseph Schumpeter as a source of economic well-being.
Joseph Schumpeter, an economist who wrote about the role of creative destruction in capitalism, would have suggested that attempts to control business cycles were actually destructive.
All these scholars writing Kitab al-Amwal were within the Great Gap of Joseph Schumpeter.
Les auteurs rappellent, a juste titre selon nous, l'importance des travaux de Joseph Schumpeter dans toute reflexion sur l'innovation.
This publication analyses the theories of four eminent economists of the 20th century--Irving Fisher, Hyman Minsky, Joseph Schumpeter and Thorstein Veblen--on deflation and its consequences in the form of recessions and depressions.
Over the last two decades Joseph Schumpeter has been well-served by biographers.
Bradford DeLong, "Creative Destruction's Reconstruction: Joseph Schumpeter Revisited," the panel underscores the following:
Joseph Schumpeter, "Chapter VII: The Process of Creative
While it's difficult to tinker with success during the growth and development cycle of an enterprise, that is precisely when "creative destruction," as advocated by renowned economist Joseph Schumpeter, must be instigated.
The philosophy, explains Feilmeier, goes back to Joseph Schumpeter, the economist who coined the theory of "creative destruction" (that creative destruction is real, and the markets ultimately destroy everything because people invest in new ways to do things--and if you don't continue to do that internally, eventually it's going to happen to you).